derivation of Black-Scholes formula in martingale form
Contents:
- 0.1 Assumptions
- 0.1.1 Asset price
- 0.1.2 Money-market account
- 0.1.3 Portfolio process
- 0.2 Derivation
- 0.2.1 Change of probability measure
- 0.2.2 Discounted portfolio process is a martingale
- 0.2.3 Portfolio process as a conditional expectation
- 0.3 Existence of solutions
- 0.3.1 Proposed construction
- 0.3.2 Verification
This entry derives the Black-Scholes formula in martingale form.
The portfolio process representing a stock optionwill be shown to satisfy:
(1) |
(The quantities appearing here are defined precisely,in the section on “Assumptions” below.)
Equation (1)can be used in practice to calculate for all times ,because from the specification of a financial contract,the value of the portfolio at time ,or in other words, its pay-off at time ,will be a known function.Mathematically speaking, gives the terminal conditionfor the solution of a stochastic differential equation.
0.1 Assumptions
0.1.1 Asset price
The asset or stock price is to be modelled by the stochasticdifferential equation:
(2) |
where and are constants.
The stochastic process is a standard Brownian motion
adapted to the filtration
.
See the main articleon the Black-Scholes formula (http://planetmath.org/BlackScholesFormula)for an explanation and justification of this modelling assumption.
0.1.2 Money-market account
The money-market account accumulates interest compounded continuouslyat a rate of .It satisfies the stochastic differential equation:
(3) |
This happens to take the same form as an ordinary differential equation,for the process has no randomness in it at all,under the assumption of a fixed interest rate .
The solution is to equation (3) with initial condition is .
0.1.3 Portfolio process
The price of the option is derived by following a replicating portfolioconsisting of units of the stock and units of the money-marketaccount. If denotes the value of this portfolio at time ,then
(4) |
A certain “self-financing condition” on the portfolio requires that also satisfy the stochastic differential equation:
(5) |
This condition essentially says that we cannot input extra amountsof money out of thin air into our portfolio; we must start with what we have.
Equation (5) is not a mathematically proven statement,but another modelling assumption, justified by an analogous equationgoverning trading in discretized time periods.
0.2 Derivation
We first manipulate thestochastic differential equation (4)for the portfolio process ,to express it in terms of the Brownian motion .
from eq. (5) and (3) | ||||
from eq. (4) | ||||
from eq. (2) | ||||
rearrangement |
0.2.1 Change of probability measure
Define the Brownian motion with drift :
(6) |
so that , and
(7) |
The introduction of the process is not merely for notational convenience but is mathematicallymeaningful. If the probability space we are working inis ,and , for , is astandard Wiener process on ,then will not be a standard Wiener processon , but it will be a standard Wiener processunder with a different probability measure.
The probability measure is obtained by Girsanov’s theorem.The exact form for can be calculated,but it will not be needed in this derivation.
In finance, is known as the risk-neutral measure,and the quantity is the market price of risk.
0.2.2 Discounted portfolio process is a martingale
From equation (7),we see that the value of the portfolio grows at the risk-freeinterest rate of ,apart from the randomness associated due to the stochasticdifferential .
It is thus reasonable to expect that,if we normalize the portfolio value amountby the amount that cash grows due to accumulation of risk-freeinterest,the resulting process, , should have a zero growth rate.That this is indeed the case can be verifiedby a computation with Itô’s formula— more specifically, the for Itô integrals:
from eq. (7) | ||||
from . |
Thus,
Or, in integral form:
(8) |
Assuming is a -adapted process— where is the filtration generated by the Brownianmotion (or equivalently ) —the Itô integral in equation (8)is a martingle under the probability space .
0.2.3 Portfolio process as a conditional expectation
Then by the definition of a martingale,we have
where denotes the conditionalexpectation, of a random variableon the measurable space
,underthe probability measure .
In particular, setting and ,and rearranging the factors of ,we obtain the desired result, equation (1).
0.3 Existence of solutions
So far,we have derived the form of the solution for the portfolio value process ,assuming that it exists.Actually, if we were to take onlyequations (4) and (5)as the problem to solve mathematically,without any reference to the financial motivations,it is possible to work backwards and deduce the existenceof the solution.
0.3.1 Proposed construction
Let be the risk-neutral probability measure,and let be any given random variable,representing the terminal condition.Define the family of random variables dependent on time,
(9) |
It is easy to verify that, for any ,the process is a martingalewith respect to , the filtration generatedby the Wiener process under the probabilitymeasure .
0.3.2 Verification
We now invoke the martingale representation theorem for Itô processes:for any martingale , with respect to underthe probability measure ,there exists a -adapted process such that has the representation:
Letting andcomparing with equations (8)and (4),we are motivated to definethe -adapted processes:
Then the process constructedby equation (9)trivially satisfies equation (4).And it is a simple matter to check thatequation (5) holds as well:
Itô’s product rule | ||||
add and subtract | ||||
the term | ||||
where in the last equality we have used the SDE for in terms of in place of :
obtained by substitutingin equation (2),the differential of equation (6).
References
- 1 Bernt Øksendal.Stochastic Differential Equations,An Introduction with Applications, 5th edition. Springer, 1998.
- 2 Steven E. Shreve. Stochastic Calculus for Finance II:Continuous-Time Models. Springer, 2004.